Economics of Open Access Literature Review
FEBRUARY 23, 2009
Bergstrom & Bergstrom 2004 PNAS
- Huge commercial markup
- Difference widened particularly in 80s/90s
- Commercial publishers use bundling to increase profits
- Decreases variation in WTP
- Non-profit publishers use bundling
- To subsidise societal public goods
McCabe 2002 AER
- Diff-diff analysis of journal prices post merger activity
- Results
- 10% price increase
1. Controlling for quality
McCabe & Snyder 2005 AER
- Model of journal pricing
- Which journals go open source?
- Result
- Intuition
- As journal quality increases
- Reader surplus increases
- Author surplus decreases
- Less likely to get published
- => Switch pricing balance accordingly
Willinsky 2005 OJSDO
- Details savings of switching to open-source system
Tenopir & King 2000 Book
- History
- Journals started in late C16
- Hidden colleges emerged in early C17
- Comms
- Private correspondence
- Recognised need for formal correspondence
- Alternatives to journals crap
- Books too slow
- Copyists too expensive
- Drive to electronic media in 1960-80
- <= explosion of research on library science
- Initial difficulties
- Economies of scale in computing did not emerge
- Standardization difficulties
- Scientists
- Reading positively related to performance
- Browsing (perusal) is the most important way of locating readings
- Articles more likely to be read closer to time of initial publication vs much later
- But depth of reading goes the other way
- Also older articles more likely to be used for research
- Publishers
- Trends 1975-1995
- Pages per scientist increased 50%
- Journal price x7
- Only 50% explicable by
- Article costs
- $4500 per article
- $325 per article page
- Electronic publishing
- Advantages to electronic media
- Speed/convenience of delivery
- Opportunity to experiment with electronic media
- Timeliness of publication
- Location independence
- Instant updates/revisions
- Improved searchability
- Ability to create own personal electronic file of articles
- Space savings
- Not reliant on library collection
- Savings
- 4% for low circulation
- 30% and beyond for large circulations
Chrissanthis & Chrissanthis 1994 JEE
- Thorough empirical model of econ journal prices
- Non-profit have no significant difference in prices
Dewaitrapont et al 2007 JEEA
- Econometric analysis of journal pricing
- Results
- Commercial charge x3
- Commercial on behalf of non-profit society charge x2
- Very large differences across fields
- A factor of 6 unexplained
- Law cheapest
- Physics/chemistry most expensive
- Market concentration
- ve effect
Jeon & Rochet 2007 WP
- Theoretical model of academic journal pricing
- First best pricing
- Negative reader price
- Positive externalities of readers on authors
- Second best pricing
- Open access
- Fake readers make -ve price impossible
- Comparative statics
- Non-profit switches to open access
- Quality/readers decrease
- Intuition
- Readers don’t bear cost of reading
- Would have higher standards if they were paying
UK Commons 2004
- Advantages of digitization
- Assists collation
- Lowers distribution cost
- New media e.g. hyperlinks
- Improved searching
- Easier usage stats
- Research accessibility limited in NHS
- Due to subscription prices
- Central repositories greatly facilitate research
- Study of costs of OA
- It costs 30% less
- Making author pay => greater competition among journals
- You have to bear the cost of applying to a journal with a higher rejection rate
- Publication integrity argument bollocks
- Because of reputation effect
- Why should authors subsidise submissions?
- Make two fees
1. Submission fee covers refereeing cost
2. Publication fee covers publication cost
- Need to worry about academic societies
- Losing an important source of cross-subsidizing income
Bergstrom 2001 JEP
- Commercial publishers charge a huge markup
- Commercial publishers initially charged competitive rates
- Took advantage of inability of non-profit publishers to keep up with demand
- Ex post lockin permits price hikes